• Nem Talált Eredményt

Economics of the welfare state

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Ossza meg "Economics of the welfare state"

Copied!
13
0
0

Teljes szövegt

(1)

Economics of the welfare state

(2)

Economics of the welfare state

Sponsored by a Grant TÁMOP-4.1.2-08/2/A/KMR-2009-0041 Course Material Developed by Department of Economics,

Faculty of Social Sciences, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest (ELTE) Department of Economics, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest

Institute of Economics, Hungarian Academy of Sciences Balassi Kiadó, Budapest

(3)
(4)

Economics of the welfare state

Authors: Róbert Gál, Márton Medgyesi Supervised by: Róbert Gál

June 2011

ELTE Faculty of Social Sciences, Department of Economics

(5)

Economics of the welfare state

Week 6

Political economy of income- redistribution in cross-section

Róbert Gál, Márton Medgyesi

(6)

Introduction

• Why did the extent of welfare redistribution increase in the 20th century in industrial countries?

• What level of redistribution is likely to be realized in developed democracies?

• Modeling the democratic institutional system :

– Direct democracy: voters vote for programs, not for parties.

– Majority rule: the winner is the program with more than 50% of votes.

Assumptions:

• Programs differ in one dimension

• Individuals have single-peaked preferences (there is one preferred policy which provides the greatest utility, and the farther the policies are from that one, the less they are preferred)

Median voter theorem: in case of majority voting (with the above mentioned assumptions) the preferred option of the median voter cannot lose.

(7)

Median voter theorem (illustration)

• Three voters A, B, and C vote on the amount of a public good. Let us assume that their preferences can be represented by the curves

below. Out of two alternatives each voter chooses the one which provides him/her more utility (which is closer to his/her most

preferred amount of public good).

• The amount (Q*) most preferred by median voter B gets majority against all other options. If Q<Q* (e.g. Q’), B and C vote for Q* and only A chooses Q’, if Q>Q* (e.g. Q’’), B and A vote for Q* and only C chooses Q’.

Utility

Quantity of public good

A B C

Q’ Q* Q’’

(8)

Median voter theorem and redistribution

Assumption:

The government imposes tax rate t on income and redistributes the total tax receipt in the form of a constant r amount of transfer (r= t), where  is the average income.

y income is exogenous

U=U(c)

c=(1-t)y+r

What kind of tax rate maximizes the welfare of individuals?

Max U=max U[(1–t)y+ t]=max U[y+t(–y)]

For individuals with >y, t=1 (tax rate of 100%) maximizes U For individuals with <y, t=0 maximizes U

Conclusions:

In the case of a typical, skewed-to-the-right income distribution > median, therefore programs promising higher rate of redistribution get the majority.

In the case of increasing inequalities support for redistribution will be stronger .

The program which promises total redistribution (100% tax rate) would also get majority.

(9)

Why do not we have 100% tax rates?

Two types of explanation:

A) The rational median voter does not want total redistribution.

B) The dominant preference is not that of the median income individual.

A) The rational median voter does not want total redistribution:

1. Endogenous income (Meltzer and Richard 1981)

Assume that income is endogenous, individuals choose between consumption and leisure in accordance with their preferences U=U(c,L). Period of time spent in work is n=1–L, and income is y=nx, where x0 expresses the productivity of the individual (exogenous).

The government imposes tax rate t on incomes and redistributes the total tax receipt in the form of a constant r amount of transfer (r =

t), where  is the average income.

Individual supply of labor in the case of given t and r:

Max U(c,L)= max U[(1 – t)nx+r, 1 – n]

First-order optimum condition: u/ n= Ucx(1 – t) – UL=0  x(1 – t)= UL/Uc

(10)

Why do not we have 100% tax rates?

• If U=ln(c+)+aln(L+) (Stone-Geary utility function), where , , are parameters, then Uc=1/ (c+), UL=a/ (L+)

• This leads to the utility-maximizing supply of labor. In addition, it can be demonstrated that there exists an ability level x0=a(r+ )/(1 – t)(1 + ) below which labor supply is zero.

• It can be shown too that y (pre-tax income) increases in proportion to productivity (x).

Political decision making: voting for the tax rate Dual effect of the increasing tax rate:

• Total tax returns increase for a while.

• However, the average income () decreases! There will be people

working less, and the number of people not working at all increases for

x0/t= a(r+ )/(1 + )(1 – t)2 >0.

• The amount of transfers payable as a function of the tax rate :

r/t=t*/t+ because /t<0. Consequently, r increases with t when - /t< /t<0

r reaches its maximum, if r/t=0, when /t= - /t r decreases with t, when /t< - /t

(11)

Why do not we have 100% tax rates?

Preferences depend on income, which in turn depends on productivity (x).

Everybody chooses the tax rate from among the feasible alternatives (r= t) that provides the greatest utility.

Those who do not work (x<x0) do not experience the income-reducing effect of

taxation. They are represented by indifference curves U3 and U4, their preferred rate of taxation is t0.

Workers with x0<x<xmean have low income and indifference curves such as U1 and U2,. Their preferred tax-rate is tm.

Those who have x>xmean, are workers earning high wages. They prefer zero rate of taxation as they gain nothing from this kind of redistribution.

The accepted rate of taxation will be determined by the preference of the median ability level. But it will be lower than 100% even if the median voter does not work!

Source: Mueller, 1989

(12)

Why do not we have 100% tax rates?

2. Inequalities can be favorable for economic growth

The median voter might be willing to accept inequality if faster growth positively affects his welfare as well.

The rich are more willing to save. Supposing equal average income, higher inequality means higher level of saving resulting in higher economic growth.

Imperfect credit market: credits are attainable only for those, who posses a certain level of income. Redistribution of income could diminish the number of solvent individuals (typically at the income level of developing countries), so less people can start up new enterprises and invest.

3. Conflict between the middle class and the poor

Example: public subsidies for higher education. If the middle class is able to pay tuition fees, it will not support full public financing of higher education, fearing that extended education will devalue higher degrees.

4. POUM=Perspective of Upward Mobility Hypothesis

If the system of income redistribution lasts for a long period, people with below- average income and expecting upward mobility (that is to grow above the

average income over time), will not support redistributive programs.

(13)

Why do not we have 100% tax rates?

B) The dominant preference is not that of the median income individual

1. Turn-up in elections is income dependent:

People with higher income vote more frequently: the median income of voters is higher than the general median income.

2. Political programs differ in more than one dimension:

E.g. right-wing politics: low redistribution + support for churches

Left-wing politics: high redistribution + no support for churches

A left-wing party can suggest lower redistribution in order

to attract anti-clerical right-wing voters.

Hivatkozások

KAPCSOLÓDÓ DOKUMENTUMOK

• inequalities of capital and property income significantly increased in Northern Europe, Hungary, and Italy;. • the share of capital and property income in total

• The share of cash transfers in total income decreased between 1995 and 2005 in most OECD countries. Sharpest decrease took place in Sweden, Finland, Denmark, and Ireland

• Monotonicity: if income is given to an individual below poverty threshold, then the value of poverty index decreases (strong monotonicity). Weak monotonicity requires that

• If a household with characteristics x obtains a welfare level of u(q,x) by the consumption of consumer basket q, then the minimum level of expenditure

Aim: to measure the redistributive effect of cash transfers and taxes. Analysing the distribution of transfers and taxes:.. • Graphic representation of the distribution of

Faculty of Social Sciences, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest (ELTE) Department of Economics, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest.. Institute of Economics, Hungarian Academy

Cash benefits other than Social Insurance Benefits with the aim of poverty alleviation Advantages and disadvantages of targeting Methods of targeting.. Unemployment benefits

– age profiles of transfer-flows and accumulation of life cycle wealth in traditional and industrial societies – family as the organizer of ”welfare programs”:..