• Nem Talált Eredményt

Economics of the welfare state

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Ossza meg "Economics of the welfare state"

Copied!
41
0
0

Teljes szövegt

(1)

Economics of the welfare state

(2)

Economics of the welfare state

Sponsored by a Grant TÁMOP-4.1.2-08/2/A/KMR-2009-0041 Course Material Developed by Department of Economics,

Faculty of Social Sciences, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest (ELTE) Department of Economics, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest

Institute of Economics, Hungarian Academy of Sciences Balassi Kiadó, Budapest

(3)
(4)

Economics of the welfare state

Authors: Róbert Gál, Márton Medgyesi Supervised by: Róbert Gál

June 2011

ELTE Faculty of Social Sciences, Department of Economics

(5)

Economics of the welfare state

Week 1

Measuring social inequality

Róbert Gál, Márton Medgyesi

(6)

Topics

What is the subject of inequality measurement?

Inequality indices

• Basic indicators of dispersion

• Graphical representation of inequalities

• Basic indicators of dispersion

• Representation of inequalities by the Lorenz curve

• The Gini coefficient

• Axiomatic approach to inequality measurement

• Attributes of aggregate inequality indicators

• Generalized Entropy indices

• Decomposing inequalities

(7)

What is the subject of the measurement of inequality?

Basically we are interested in the distribution of material living standards (consumption-possibilities) among individuals.

Inequality of what?

The best basis of measuring consumption-possibilities could be wealth in the broad sense: everything that produces income in the present or the future:

• financial wealth: bank deposit, securities, etc.,

• material wealth: durable consumer goods, real estate, etc.,

• human capital: inherited abilities and learnt skills, knowledge

• entitlements to government transfers: e.g. to social security pension income.

All types of wealth result in a flow of income.

In what form?

(8)

Inequality of what?

YF = YM+YN

YF = total income

YM= monetary income: earnings, capital-income, financial transfers from the government

YN = non-monetary income: job satisfaction, leisure time, service of material wealth, value of self-produced consumption, non-financial transfers from the government YF the measure of individual consumption-possibilities

YF however is not a proper measure of individual well- being: e.g. it does not take into account uncertainty

In practice there are difficulties of measurement!

In case of non-monetary incomes: in almost every types.

In case of financial incomes, measurement of capital income (e.g. unrealized gain on securities) and the entrepreneurial income is difficult.

(9)

Inequality among individuals?

We measure income on household level even though we are interested in the distribution of living standards among individuals!

Solution: income per capita?

A

in separate household

B

in separate household

A and B together

Rent 30 30 50

Utilities 20 20 30

Food 15 15 30

Consumption goods 35 35 90

Total expenditure 100 100 200

(10)

Inequality among individuals?

Income per capita is NOT a proper measure

• Household public goods

• Distribution within the household: e.g. needs differ according to ages Equivalent income =total household income/number of consumption units in the household

OECD II scale:

first adult: 1 consumption unit,

further adults: 0.5 consumption units

children (below 15) 0.3 consumption units

per capita income

OECD II.

scale

equivalent income

e=0,5 scale

equivalent income

One adult 1000 1,0 1000 1.00 1000

Two adults 1000 1,5 1333 1.41 1414

Three adults 1000 2,0 1500 1.73 1732

Two adults, 1 child < 5y 1000 1,8 1667 1.73 1732 Two adults, 2 children < 5y 1000 2,1 1905 2.00 2000 Two adults, 1 <5y, 1 15y 1000 2,6 1923 2.24 2236

(11)

Graphical representation of a distribution

Representation of information on

expenditure, consumption or income in

the form of diagrams is often very useful

in the analysis of inequalities.

(12)

Representations of basic indicators of dispersion

• Pen’s parade

• Frequency distribution

• Cumulative frequency distribution

• Lorenz curve

(13)

Height (income)

Rank of individuals poorest

richest

average

median

Representation of the distribution of incomes with the help of Pen’s Parade: ranking people by their income

Charting the income distribution

Source:

Tóth, 2005

(14)

Incomes

Rank of individuals

Flatter section: many people, small differences

Steep sections on the curve:

few people, large differences

Characteristics of dispersion

Charting the income distribution

Source:

Tóth, 2005

(15)

0 50000 100000 150000 200000 250000 300000 350000 400000 450000 500000 550000 600000 650000

1 18 35 52 69 86 10 3

12 0

13 7

15 4

17 1

18 8

20 5

22 2

23 9

25 6

27 3

29 0

30 7

32 4

34 1

35 8

37 5

39 2

40 9

42 6

44 3

46 0

47 7

49 4

51 1

52 8

54 5

56 2

income

Persons (ranked)

Pen’s parade in Hungary: income of people ranked by their per capita income in 1992

Charting the income distribution

Source: Tóth, 2005

(16)

Frequency distribution:

The diagram (histogram) illustrates the relative

frequency of individuals sorted into different

categories of expenditure.

For example the enclosed frequency distribution

shows that 20% of

individuals fall into the fourth category. [i.e.

f(4)=0.2].

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 Categories of expenditure

Percentage of population

Fre que ncy distribution f(y)

Charting the income distribution

Source: Tóth, mimeo.

(17)

-100 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700

5 35 65 95 125 155 185 215 245 455 275 305 335 365 395 425 455 485

(ezer Ft)

Income distribution in 1992, illustration from the Hungarian Household Panel*

*Number of people in the HHP sample

Charting the income distribution

Source: Tóth, mimeo.

(18)

0 200 400 600 800 1000 1200

5 15 25 35 45 55 65 75 85 95 105 115 125 135 145 155 165 175 185 195 205 92

93 94 95 96 Number of persons

(1000)

Income (1000 Ft)

Income distribution in Hungary, 1992–1996*

*equivalent incomes deflated to 1992

Charting the income distribution

Source: Tóth, mimeo.

(19)

Cumulative frequency distribution: This graph

illustrates cumulative frequency – percentage of households on or below a given level of expense/income. Compared to the previous graph F(y) is the area below f(y) on the left side.

[F(4) = f(4)+f(3)+f(2)+f(1) = 20+35+12+4=71%]

0

10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 Categories of expenditure

cumulative frequency (%)

Cumulativ e fre que ncy function F(y)

Charting the income distribution

Source: Tóth, mimeo.

(20)

Ratios of dispersion

Definition:

Ratios of dispersion measure the distance between two groups in the income distribution.

Typically the average income of the richest x%

of the population is divided by the average expenses/income of the poorest x%.

Different alternatives exist. Most frequently it is

based on the decile or the quintile of the

distribution (decile includes 10% of the total

population, quintile includes 20% of it).

(21)

Ratios of dispersion

The definition of a ratio of dispersion:

Based on group averages:

j group bottom

of income Average

i group top

of income Average

Based on cutpoints

(percentile ratio): Upper cutpoint for bottomgroup j i group for top

cutpoint Lower

Group i and group j can be defined as deciles (1/10), quintiles (1/5), quartiles (1/4), etc.

(22)

Incomes

Ranking of individuals

A few basic measures of income inequality

Lowest

decile 2nd decile

Highest decile

...

Note: high variation

on the margins, moderate

variation elsewhere Ratio of

the average of deciles

Percentile ratio

Ratios of dispersion

Source: Tóth, 2005

(23)

Ratios of dispersion

Advantages:

(+) The group-average ratios and percentile ratios are easy to interpret.

Disadvantages:

(–) The value of the group-average-ratio is highly sensitive to extreme incomes, particularly in case of small-sample estimations.

(–) No axiomatic basis, not derived from principles of equity.

(24)

Representation of inequalities by the Lorenz curve

Lorenz curve: The most common representation. The curve illustrates the

cumulative ratio of

expenditure on the vertical axis and the cumulative ratio of population on the horizontal axis. In this example 40% of the population possess less than 20% of the total

consumption expenditure.

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100

0 20 40 60 80 100

Cumulative % of population

Cumulative % of consumption

(25)

Representation of inequalities by the Lorenz curve

If all individuals had the same income, i.e. the distribution of incomes was perfectly equal, the Lorenz curve would be identical to the diagonal (E: line of equality).

If one person had the total

income, the Lorenz curve would pass through points (0,0), (100, 0), and (100,100). This is the curve of „perfect inequality”.

Line (S): lower inequality Line (L): higher inequality What if they intersect?

E: Line of equality

L:Higher inequality S: Lower inequality

Cumulative decile shares (population)

Gini: surface between E and S divided by surface of the lower triangle Cumulative decile

shares (income)

Source: Tóth, 2005

(26)

Indices of aggregate inequality:

the Gini coefficient

The Gini coefficient is

related to the Lorenz curve representation.

The value of Gini equals the ratio of the area A and area A+B.

In the previous figure Gini equals 0 in the case of

perfect equality and 1 in the case of perfect inequality.

A

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100

0 20 40 60 80 100

Cumulative % of population

Cumulative % of consumption

A

B

(27)

Indices of aggregate inequality:

the Gini coefficient

Definition:

The Gini coefficient is the most commonly used indicator of inequality.

The definition of Gini: ratio of the average absolute

income difference between every pair of the sample and the average income.

The Gini coefficient can range from 0 to 1. The value of 0 expresses total equality and the value of 1 maximal inequality. It measures the „deviation” from total

equality.

(28)

Formal definition:

Different formulae exist; the classical formula of Gini is :

Where yi and yj stand for individual income/consumption values, is the average, and n is the number of observations.

Indices of aggregate inequality:

the Gini coefficient

y n

n

y y

Gini

n

i

n

j

j i

) 1 (

2

1 1

 

y

(29)

Indices of aggregate inequality:

the Gini coefficient

Advantages (+) and disadvantages (–) :

(+) The coefficient is easy to understand because of its connection to the Lorenz curve.

(–) The coefficient is not additively separable: the Gini of the total population is not equal to the (weighted) sum of the Ginis of population subgroups.

(30)

Indices of aggregate inequality:

the Gini coefficient

The coefficient is sensitive to income-changes

irrespective of whether the change is taking

place at the top, the middle, or the bottom of

the distribution (all transfers of income

between two individuals have an effect

independently of their financial situation).

(31)

Axiomatic approach to the measurement of inequalities

In which distribution do you think inequality is higher?

1. A(5,8,10) B(10,16,20) 2. A(5,8,10) B(10,13,15)

3. A(5,8,10) B(5,5,8,8,10,10) 4. A(1,4,7,10,13) B(1,5,6,10,13) 5. A(4,8,9) vs B(5,6,10) ?

A’(4,7,7,8,9) vs B’(5,6,7,7,10) ?

See: Amiel és Cowell, 1999

(32)

Axiomatic approach to the measurement of inequalities

What kind of attributes should we expect of this kind of index?

1. Scale independence: if all incomes are multiplied by constant k, the inequality index should not change.

2. Population independence: if population increases in all income categories by the same ratio, the inequality index should not change.

(33)

Axiomatic approach to the measurement of inequalities

3. Symmetry: if two individuals transpose their income the value of the inequality index should not change.

4. Axiom of transfers (Pigou–Dalton): if income is redistributed from a richer individual to a poorer one (progressive transfer), so that their ranking does not change, the inequality index should decrease.

5. Decomposability: requirement of a coherent relationship between inequality in the total population and inequality in subgroups. If inequality in one subgroup increases (all

other things unchanged) total inequality should not decrease. Special type: additive separability.

(34)

Indices of aggregate inequality: the generalized entropy indices

Question: which axioms do or do not selected indices fulfill?

Theorem:

An index is consistent simultaneously with the axiom of scale

independence, population independence, axiom of transfers, and the axiom of additive decomposability if and only if it is member of the generalized entropy family of indices.

The formula of the Generalized Entropy Indices:

Where yi = income/consumption,

N = number of individuals, and is a parameter which weights the individuals of different levels of distribution.



 



 

  

 

  

N

i

i

y y GE N

1

2

1 1 1

) (

 

(35)

Indices of aggregate inequality:

the generalized entropy indices

2 1

1

2 1

1

1 1

) 2 2 (

log 1 .

) 1 (

1 log )

0 (

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

N

i

i N

i

i i

N

i i

y N y

y GE CV

y y y

y Theil N

GE

y y MLD N

GE

Depending on the value of parameter:

(36)

Indices of aggregate inequality:

the generalized entropy indices

Attributes of certain indicators

parameter index sensitivity

= 0 MLD middle incomes (mean log

deviation)

= 1 Theil index middle incomes

= 2 CV higher incomes (coefficient

of variation)

(37)

Indicators of aggregate inequality:

the standardized entropy indices

Advantages and disadvantages:

(+) Axiomatic basis: we know its attributes.

(+) GE(α) indices can be separated to ”subgroups” : the GE(α) index calculated on the total population is the

weighted average of the indices calculated on its

subgroups, where weights are the proportions of subgroups in the total population (this is not possible in the case of

Gini).

(–) Difficult to interpret (in contrast to Gini)

(38)

Decomposition of inequalities

• Inequalities are decomposed when one is curious about the extent to which inequalities among various social

groups, regions or income components are responsible for the total inequalities in a country.

• Inequalities can be separated to ”between group” and

”within group” components. The first one shows the

difference between the averages of people from different subgroups, and the second one shows the differences within the groups.

(39)

0 500000 1000000 1500000 2000000 2500000 3000000

25 50 75 100 125 150 175 200 225 250 275 300 325 350 375 400 401

ossz87 ossz01

1987

2001

Decomposition of inequalities:

distribution of income in total population, 1987 and 2001

Source: Tóth, 2005

(40)

200000 400000 600000 800000 1000000 1200000 1400000

Decomposition of inequalities: frequency distribution at different levels of education

0

25 50 75 100 125 150 175 200 225 250 275 300 325 350 375 400 401

0 200000 400000 600000 800000 1000000 1200000 1400000

25 50 75 100 125 150 175 200 225 250 275 300 325 350 375 400 401

1987 2001

primary

skilled worker

intermediate

higher education

Source: Tóth, 2005

(41)

Decomposition of inequalities

Decomposition of an additively separable index (MLD):

MLD= k vkMLDk + k vk log (1/k), Within group Between group

inequality inequality

Where vk =nk/n and k=k/

Ábra

Income distribution in 1992, illustration from the Hungarian Household  Panel*

Hivatkozások

KAPCSOLÓDÓ DOKUMENTUMOK

Faculty of Social Sciences, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest (ELTE) Department of Economics, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest.. Institute of Economics, Hungarian Academy

Cash benefits other than Social Insurance Benefits with the aim of poverty alleviation Advantages and disadvantages of targeting Methods of targeting.. Unemployment benefits

A) The rational median voter does not want total redistribution. B) The dominant preference is not that of the median income individual. A) The rational median voter does not

– age profiles of transfer-flows and accumulation of life cycle wealth in traditional and industrial societies – family as the organizer of ”welfare programs”:..

Resource reallocation between generations of the traditional society: insurance performance of the family as the organizer.. of

Note: FABR: private asset based reallocations; GABR: public asset based reallocations; TG: public transfers; TF: private transfers... Channels of financing the per capita

• UCT does not effect education: every parent chooses the optimal level of human capital investment. • CCT lessens the direct cost of studying: the lost wage is not w, but

• high discount rate or self-control problems can also result in the low level of human capital investment.. Altruism-assumption is