• Nem Talált Eredményt

AGRICULTURAL PRICES AND MARKETS

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Ossza meg "AGRICULTURAL PRICES AND MARKETS"

Copied!
29
0
0

Teljes szövegt

(1)

AGRICULTURAL PRICES

AND MARKETS

(2)

AGRICULTURAL PRICES AND MARKETS

Sponsored by a Grant TÁMOP-4.1.2-08/2/A/KMR-2009-0041 Course Material Developed by Department of Economics,

Faculty of Social Sciences, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest (ELTE) Department of Economics, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest

Institute of Economics, Hungarian Academy of Sciences Balassi Kiadó, Budapest

(3)
(4)

AGRICULTURAL PRICES AND MARKETS

Author: Imre Fertő

Supervised by Imre Fertő June 2011

ELTE Faculty of Social Sciences, Department of Economics

(5)

AGRICULTURAL PRICES AND MARKETS

Week 8

Price differences and quality

Imre Fertő

(6)

Literature

• Theory:

– Tomek, W. G.–Robinson, K. (2003): Agricultural

Product Prices. Cornell University Press, Chapter 7.

Hudson (2007): Agricultural Markets and Prices.

Blackwell, Chapter 8

• Application:

– Parcell, J. L.–Schroeder, T. C. (2007): Hedonic retail beef and pork product prices. Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 39 (1) 29–46

(7)

Outline

• Issue of quality in the economics

• Quality grading in the food chain

• Operational and price efficiency

• The impact of quality grading on D and S

• Relationships between quality grades

• Quality grades and marketing margin

• Classification issues

(8)

Issue of quality in the economics: an example

• Impact of non-observable quality (Akerlof 1976)

• Assume. Farmers produce wheat:

– Production costs:

• Good quality: 1,5 Ft/kg

• Bad quality: 1,4 Ft/kg – Processor pays

• Good quality : 2 Ft/kg

• Bad quality : 1 Ft/kg – Perfect information

• Farmers produce good quality

• Farmers’ profit= 2 Ft/kg–1,5 Ft/kg=0,5 Ft/kg

(9)

Continuation of example

• Imperfect information (processor can not observe the quality of wheat)

– Processor assumes that farmers

produce good quality, thus he offers P = 2 Ft/kg

– But, some farmers produce bad quality wheat, thus they are able to increase their profits

• Consequence: there is no equilibrium if all

farmers produce bad quality wheat

(10)

Continuation of example

• Imperfect information

• Assume

– Processor pays 1,5 Ft/kg for bad quality, – Processor is risk neutral

– Maximum ability to pay depends on the average quality:

• P=ρ(2Ft)+(1– ρ)1,5Ft, where

• ρ the share of farmers producing good quality

• In this case ρ=0, thus p=1,5 Ft/kg

(11)

Continuation of example

• Consequences:

– Farmers earn 10 fillér per kilogramm – Profit of processor is zero

– Equilibrium exists, but it is not optimal

– Farmers produce low quality wheat in the equilibrium, although high quality wheat would be better for players and society – Market failure (adverse selection) due to

unobservable quality

(12)

Standards and grades in food chain

• Solutions for imperfect information – Grades and standards

– Contracts

– Vertical integration

• Grading systems

– Quality: subjective thing

– Food quality standards: well-defined aspects of the quality of products

– grades: classification of products regarding to quality standards

• Two aspects:

– Delivery function of the marketing system – Transparency of comparison

(13)

Price efficiency

• A well-defined system of grades can improve the efficiency of marketing system

• Price efficiency: (allocation aspects)

– Increases the meaningfulness of price quotations

– Increases the precisions of price formation through increased knowledge

– May increase the level of competition in a market – Permits more systematic allocation of available

supplies to different demands

– Facilitates the collection of reliable information

on demand, supply and prices

(14)

Other consequences of standards

• Grading systems are not costless, and in some

instances, the cost of grading system may exceed the benefits of it

• May enhance potential price discrimination in certain markets

• May reduce the supply and flow of lower grade

produce, thus leading to price increase and reduced consumer choice

• Grades based on the quality at the production level may be meaningless to consumers

• Likewise, grades based on consumer preferences may not be meaningful for producers

(15)

Operational efficiency

• Operational efficiency (costs aspects)

– Limits time and expense of bargaining about quality

– Increases the ability to buy and sell based on description (e-business!)

– Encourages specialisation of marketing functions – May lead to larger geographical areas for

marketing

– May reduce the amount of unnecessary

information required for promotion and advertising – May discourage product differentiation based on

perceived quality differences

(16)

Measuring efficiency

Technical efficiency=OQ/OP Price efficiency=OR/OQ

Economic efficiency=OR/OP

(17)

Measuring efficiency

• Technical efficiency (TE):OQ/OP

– If TE=1, then we are at the isoquant

– If distance between Q and P, TE approaches to zero, i.e. 0<TE≤1

– Q is not most profitable technology, although it is efficient technically

• Price/allocative efficiency (AE): OR/OQ

– Best technological ratio regarding to P /best

technology regarding to best technological ratio

• Economic Efficiency (EE): OR/OP

• We can calculate efficiency for firm or industry

• Structural efficiency (SE), weighting by size of firms

• Example: three firms

– EE(1; 0,5;03) weights (4/7; 2/7; 1/7) – SE=1*(4/7)+0,5*(2/7)+0,3*(1/7)=0,757

(18)

Impact of quality grades on demand

A

B J

K

L G2

G1 Different preferences, same purchasing power

A and B consumers with different preferences, relating equilibrium points are K and L J a fixed ratio between quality grades (unclassified goods)

K and L are at higher level of indifference curve then J

(19)

Impact of quality grades on demand

A

B N G

H G2

G1

A and B consumers with different purchasing power, relating equilibrium points are G and H

T a fixed ration between quality grades N is less preferable than H

M

T

Same preferences, different purchasing power

(20)

Impact of quality grades on supply

P

Q Dg

Du

Qi Pu

Pg

Consumers are willing to pay more for graded products, thus aggregate demand shifts to right

Dg is higher than Du thus with the same quantity, and higher price, producers’ income increases

The net benefit for certain farmers depends on the premium based on grading systems

(21)

Benefits of grading

• Buying can be more convenient and cheaper

• Grades are an important prerequisite for future markets

• Ensure to identify the loss happening during transportation

• Farmers better off with producing higher quality goods

• Ensure the market intelligence

• Measure for farmers’ education in order to

improve the quality of their products

(22)

Price relationships among grades

Distribution of quality

No changes changes

Demand homogeneous

heterogeneous

(23)

Homogeneuos demand, same quality

quality quantity

poor high

C B A

If quality grades are good substitutes, then the market is cleared

(24)

Homogeneous demand, changing quality

quality quantity

poor high

C B A

D1: if quality is controlled then large premiums are for medium (B) and high quality (A) goods D2: there is only one grade

D3: if consumers are willing to pay large premium for high quality (A)

D1

D2

D3

Price, ordinal quality, costs of provision of grading should be positively correlated to each other

(25)

Heterogeneous demand, same quality

• No figure, because consumers are not agreed in the quality

• Quality grade may exist, but prices

depend rather on the relative demand and supply

• E.g. USA wheat grades

(26)

Heterogeneous demand, changing supply

• If market is segmented we can use quality grades

• But market competition is not so strong as in case 2, because, demand is

heterogenous, thus quality grades are imperfect substitutes

• Quality grade may help to meet demand and supply

• E.g. vegetable, fruit, tobacco

(27)

Criteria of grading

• Relevant quality characteristics

• Correct and unified measurements

• Understandable terminology

• It should include the average of production

• Costs of grading should be acceptable

(28)

Problems of using grades

• Identification of the quality

• Number of classes and grades

• Quality deterioration

• Grading along food chain

• The relationship between grades and

brands

(29)

Conclusions

• Agricultural markets are being

increasingly characterised by product heterogeneity

• Consumers have a greater demand on

markets to produce products with specific qualities

• Grading and classification systems have increasing importance because they may improve the operational and price

efficiency of marketing system

Hivatkozások

KAPCSOLÓDÓ DOKUMENTUMOK

For example, market shares can be calculated only after the market has been defined and, when considering the potential for new entry, it is necessary to

– The price of all marketing services that occurs between the farm gate and the consumers (transport costs, packages costs, wages, profit etc.). • MM can be described – in

Faculty of Social Sciences, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest (ELTE) Department of Economics, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest.. Institute of Economics, Hungarian Academy

• The lack barriers and in the case of free movements of goods prices in different regions reflect to the changes of demand and supply and transfer costs. • In certain

externalities trade barriers and transport costs, then law of one price holds, because arbitrage ensures that price of a good is the same between spatial markets (city,

• Large expected harvest relative to current stocks – Liquidate remaining stocks before price falls. due to

– Seasonal variation in prices – Annual price behaviour. – Long run trends in price – Cyclical

– Food quality standards: well-defined aspects of the quality of products – grades: classification of products regarding to quality standards. •