• Nem Talált Eredményt

Affordability and competitiveness

In document 1 | Executive summary (Pldal 24-28)

In the market model (EEMM) the wholesale electricity price is determined by the highest marginal cost of the power plants needed to satisfy demand. The price trajectories are independent of the level of decarbonisation and similar in all scenarios, only diverging after 2045 when the two scenarios with decarbonisation targets result in lower wholesale prices. This is due to the fact that towards 2050 the share of renewables is high enough to satisfy demand in most hours at a low cost, driving the average annual price down.

The price development has several implications for policy makers. Retail prices depend on the wholesale price as well as taxes, fees and network costs. It is therefore difficult to project retail price evolution based on wholesale price information alone, but it is an important determinant of end user prices and could affect affordability for consumers. The average annual price increase over the entire period is 3.2% in the ‘no target’ scenario and 2.5% in the ‘delayed’ and ‘decarbonisation’ scenarios; the lower growth rate in these two scenarios is due to a decrease in the wholesale price during the last 5 years of the modelled time period. Although the price increase is high, prices in Europe were at histori-cal lows in 2016 for the starting point of the analysis and will rise to approximately 60 EUR/

MWh by 2030, similar to price levels 10 years ago. Still, macroeconomic analysis in Section 5.7 shows that if affordability is measured as the share of household electricity expendi-ture in disposable income, electricity expendiexpendi-ture increases more moderately compared with current levels, due to a high increase in household income. The price increase also has three positive implications, incentivising investment for new capacities, incentivising energy efficiency and reducing the need for RES support.

The investment needed in new capacities increases significantly between 2020 and 2030 in the ‘no target’ scenario. The following decade is expected to be less investment-heavy in this scenario, but investments are expected to pick up again between 2040 and 2050. In the

‘decarbonisation’ scenario, the investments are expected to peak between 2020 and 2030. In the ‘delayed’ scenario investments peak between 2040 and 2050, reflecting the significant effort needed to meet decarbonisation targets at the end of the period.

It is important to note that investments are assumed to be based on a profitability requirement (apart from the capacities planned in the national strategies) and financed by private actors. These actors factor in the different cost structure of renewables, i.e. higher capital expenditure and low operating expenditure in their investment decisions. From a social point of view, the consequences of a change in the overall investment level are limited to the impact on GDP, employment, as well as to the impact on the fiscal and external balance. These impacts are discussed in more detail in section 5.7.

Despite the very significant investment needs associated with the ‘decarbonisation’ scenario, the renewables support needed to incentivise these investments decreases over time. The RES support needed to achieve complete decarbonisation in this scenario relative to the wholesale price plus RES support is 13% in the period 2020-2025 but only 2% in 2045-2050.

Although RES technologies are already at grid parity in some locations with costs falling further, some support will still be needed in 2050 to incentivise new investment. This is partly due to the locational impact: the best locations with highest potential are used first, therefore, the levelised cost of new RES capacities might increase over time. The relation-ship between the cost of RES technologies and installed capacity is shown in Figure 10;

the figure does not account for the learning curve impacts which were also considered in the Green-X model.

Even though no new RES support is assumed in the ‘no target’ scenario after 2025, RES-based capacities are expected to more than triple between 2025 and 2050. The ‘decar-bonisation’ scenario foresees a decrease in support levels over time from 2030 onwards, from 9.3 EUR/MWh to 1.9 EUR/MWh by 2050. The rapid penetration of RES technologies even without support in the ‘no target’ scenario, and the decrease in RES support in the

‘decarbonisation’ scenario is made possible mainly by the increasing wholesale price for electricity which reduces the need for (additional) support.

Renewable energy investments may be incentivised with a number of support schemes using funding from different sources; in the model sliding feed-in premium equivalent values are calculated. Revenue from the auction of carbon allowances under the EU ETS is FIGURE 8

WHOLESALE ELECTRICITY PRICE IN MONTENEGRO, 2020-2050

(€/MWh)

a potential source of financing for renewable investment. Figure 12 contrasts cumulative RES support needs with ETS auction revenues, assuming 100% auctioning, and taking into account only allowances to be allocated to the electricity sector.

In the ‘decarbonisation’ scenario, there are no auction revenues, as only fossil fuel based plants receive an allocation under the EU Emissions Trading Scheme, and these plants disappear from the Montenegrin capacity mix by 2025 under this scenario. In the ‘delayed’

scenario, ETS revenues are expected to surpass the cost of RES support between 2030 and 2040, but the costs of support are significantly higher than the auction revenues in the following decade. As the need for RES support in this scenario rises significantly between 2040 and 2050, the balance of costs and revenues makes this option more expensive in this period than the ‘decarbonisation’ scenario.

A financial calculation was carried out on the stranded costs of fossil based generation plants that are expected to be built in the period 2017-2050. New fossil generation capac-ities included in the scenarios are defined either by national energy strategy documents and entered into the model exogenously, or are built by the investment algorithm of the EEMM. The model’s investment module assumes 10 year foresight, meaning that investors have limited knowledge of the policies applied in the distant future. The utilisation rate of fossil fuel generation assets drops below 15% in most SEERMAP countries after 2040; this means that capacities which generally need to have a 30-55 year lifetime (30 for CCGT, 40 for OCGT and 55 for coal and lignite plants) with a sufficiently high utilisation rate in order to ensure a positive return on investment will face stranded costs.

Large stranded capacities might call for public intervention with all the associated cost borne by society/electricity consumers. For this reason we have estimated the stranded costs of fossil based generation assets that were built in the period 2017-2050. The FIGURE 9

CUMULATIVE INVESTMENT COST FOR 4 AND 10 YEAR PERIODS, 2016-2050 (bn€)

FIGURE 10 LONG TERM COST OF RENEWABLE TECHNOLOGIES IN MONTENEGRO (€/MWh)

FIGURE 11 AVERAGE RES SUPPORT PER MWh OF TOTAL ELECTRICITY CONSUMPTION AND AVERAGE WHOLESALE PRICE, 2016-2050

(€/MWh)

calculation is based on the assumption that stranded costs will be collected as a surcharge on the consumed electricity (as is the case for RES surcharges) for over a period of 10 years after the these lignite based capacities become unprofitable.

Based on this calculation unprofitable lignite-fired plants would have to receive a surcharge of 2.7 EUR/MWh and 2.8 EUR/MWh over a 10 year period to cover their economic losses in the ‘no target’ and ‘delayed’ scenarios, respectively. These costs are not included in the wholesale price values shown in this report. With no new fossil based capacity com-missioned in the ‘decarbonisation’ scenario, no stranded costs occur.

In document 1 | Executive summary (Pldal 24-28)