• Nem Talált Eredményt

65 Impact Assessment of EU trade agreements on Hungary

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Ossza meg "65 Impact Assessment of EU trade agreements on Hungary"

Copied!
9
0
0

Teljes szövegt

(1)

Impact Assessment of EU trade agreements on Hungary

Gábor K

UTASI

National University of Public Service, Research Institute of Competitiveness and Economy, Budapest

kutasi.gabor@uni-nke.hu

International activity to rethink trade relations emerged in 2010s, and resulted in comprehensive agreement proposals about trade, investment protection, regulatory harmonization, and even the opening of public procurement market were included. These trade agreements were negotiated by the European Union, on behalf of the single European market and the Member States. However, because of the differences in the national industrial structures and economic development of the member economies, the individual growth impact became a relevant question in the member states. The research focuses on the EU agreements with Canada (CETA), Japan (EPA), Korean Republic, Colombia, Peru and Ecuador. The study provides an overview of the content of the CGE model and the existing models in the literature. It contains the relevant empirical analyses about the impact of trade pacts analysed in the study. The results of the CGE model will be assessed on the expected growth impact of the trade pacts mentioned. Preliminary, very limited positive growth effects were expected for Hungary in case of trade pact with Japan, Canada, Korea, and close to zero in case of South American partners. Computable general equilibrium models (CGE) are widely used to model the trade impacts. The research uses one version of CGE models to project the impact on sectoral output and the overall GDP.

This assumption is proved by the research. The conclusion of the paper is that due to the effects of the agreement with the three developed countries, no significant sectoral expansion and additional GDP growth is expected in the Hungarian economy. In case of the emerging Latin American economies, the expected impact of sectoral output and GDP growth is zero. The CGE modelling concludes that no significant effect is expected for Hungary from the EU Convention in the six cases examined.

Introduction

In 2010, international activity has been increased for rethinking trade relations will increase, and comprehensive agreements were composed to regulate and harmonize trade and investment protection, or even to liberalize particularly the public procurement market. Some of the agreements were accepted (CETA, EU-South Korea agreement etc), some are parking (TPP, TTIP). Although, these agreements were negotiated by the European Union in the name of the member states, the differences

(2)

among the national economies results in the question whether the single trade pact can have asymmetric economic impact on the member states.

The computable general equilibrium (CGE) models are useful to test the possible scenarios to estimate the future impact.

About the TTIP, Kutasi, Rezessy and Szijártó (2014) and with Kutasi (2015) have already made the impact assessment regarding to Hungary.

Their CGE model is the base to continue the analysis of economic impact on Hungary caused by further EU trade agreements. Namely, the object of the current paper is the impact assessment of the trade agreements planned or realized with Canada, Japan, South Korea, Colombia, Peru and Ecuador.

The study reviews the contents of the CGE model and the existing empirical models in the literature. In addition, it reviews empirical literature on EU conventions with the countries mentioned above. After all, the turn is on the explanation of methodology of the selected CGE model and the analysis of the data, nevertheless, composition, reliability and quality of data. Finally, the results of model calculation will be presented and evaluated in a transparent way. The preliminary assumption of the research is that a positive growth rate is expectable in case of trade pact with developed countries (Japan, Canada, Korea), but it will be a very limited impact because of trade distance and the industries (e.g.

pharmaceuticals) hardly harmonizable regulation. Regarding to EU pacts with South American countries, the expectation is a near-zero impact indicated by the model, which can be explained particularly by the geographical distance and the economic and cultural orientations.

Literature review

The economics of international trade liberalization agreements account on potential trade creation and diversion. (More see Palánkai et al., 2014.) In addition, for the agreements examined in this study, trade diversion can even reduce intra-EU trade by shifting it to transatlantic routes.

Felbermayr et al. (2013a), too, draws attention to the need for the economic mathematical model to analyse the possible scenarios and estimate trade effects. The almost exclusively applied methodological instrument the CGE model, which is based on a multi-sector model of general macroeconomics: the household sector, the government sector, the corporate sector. The theoretical model of CGE is explained in the following studies: Zalai (1998), Felbermayr et al. (2011), Felbermayr et al. (2013b), Baldwin & Francois (1997), Berden et al. (2009), Francois et al. (1996), Francois (2013).

In case of the impact assesment of international trade agreements, the essence of CGE models is to assess, through a variety of scenarios, the potential macroeconomic effects of trade regulation on growth, investment or employment. In Francois's (2013) formulation, the commercial policy benefit of the CGE model is to answer “what if?” Questions with an

(3)

independent variable of different values, with market equilibrium, by modeling price, income, and substitution effects.

CGE models can be used to examine different scenarios based on the same or different market preferences, competitive or monopolistic market structures, different levels of productivity and trade costs, and of course different levels of tariffs. The problem of geographical distance is described with the so-called iceberg cost metaphor in the trade models, which is used to illustrate how profits or the advantaged of low cost 'melts' by the increasing transportation distance. Regarding to the analysis of trade barriers, it is important to note that trade involves numerous costs factors, and only a part of them are linked to government controls that can be influenced by economic policy makers.

The so-called gravity models, which are based on the factors above, can determine the industry or product level profitability of trade regarding to geographical markets and distances, namely, the natural limits of trade.

Indirectly, it is possible to determine whether regulation and tariffs really restrict the trade or whether international trade flows are limited by natural geographical distance and different market preferences or structures independently from government control. (For more on the gravity model, see Anderson, 1979; Anderson & Wincoop, 2003;

Bergstrand, 1985.)

The key element of CGE models is estimation based on elasticity. In case of trade forecasts, the most prevalent concepts are price elasticity, trade elasticity, cost elasticity of long-distance transportation (or also known as the iceberg trade elasticity), tariff cost elasticity. The formula explained by Arkolakis et al. (2012) is calculated from the import ratio and trade elasticity, and measures well the effect of trade on macroeconomic income. This is based on the observation that, under certain conditions, an increase in the share of imports correlates to increase in income.

Armington (1969) took it into account that different geographical areas are not perfect substitutes of each other, which is important regarding to the geographical, cultural, administrative, and economic distance of countries from Hungary, in the current analysis.

As Aichele et al. (2014) explain the general equilibrium model on the effect of trade liberalization examines the relative changes in macroeconomic indicators caused by changing trade costs from tariff cuts or harmonization of non-tariff regulation. They cited the model of Dekle et al. (2008) and Caliendo and Parro (2014) which makes possible to analyse different scenarios at the aggregate and sectoral level. It is possible to test changes in tariffs, regulation or any other trade related costs (e.g.

wages). There are several versions of empirically applied CGE models, such as: the GTAP (Global Trade, Assistance and Production) model by Francois (2013), or the MIRAGE model in Fontagé et al. (2013) study.

Numerous studies have been carried out on the EU's free trade agreement, both from a comprehensive analysis and from the perspective of individual industries or product groups. There are few concrete studies on the trade agreements with the six countries examined in this study,

(4)

basically, the European Commission issued research materials. Lakatos and Nilsson (2015) used OLS regression to estimate the extent of EU- Korea trade increase, but does not include a sectoral analysis. Forizs and Nilson (2016) used the CGE model to analyse sector-specific effects across the EU, and predict strong trade growth, up to 20-30% for some sectors.

But it dose not contain estimation for additional GDP. Of course, trade growth does not necessary result in an increase of GDP, as both export and import is expected to increase significantly, which will offset each other’s the income effect. DG-Trade (2018) studies the details of the economic partnership agreement with Japan, and then, with CGE model, calculates a very low, 0.14% additional GDP growth for the EU. The same analysis was carried out by the DG-Trade (2017) study on CETA (Canada) and the European Commission (2016) paper about the trade agreement with Ecuador and Colombia and Peru. However, they use the CGE model only for trade expansion and the latter also for sector output, but do not forecast additional GDP growth.

Methodology

In terms of methodology, the study follows a relatively simply, less data- intensive model solution follows applied by Kutasi, Rezessy and Szijártó (2014), which was originally described by Arkolakis et al. (2012). The effect of the FTA on real incomes can be calculated with formula worded in equation 1, which uses the import-increasing effect and the elasticity of imports to variable trading costs (hereinafter: trade elasticities) (Arkolakis et al., 2012):

Ŵ = ^λ 1/ , (1)

where Ŵ indicates the change in real income, ^λ denotes the change in the rate of domestic use (which is equal to (1 - import ratio) value), and ε is the trade elasticity. The formula above measures well the macroeconomic income effect of growth in trade for many models. In any case, the increase in the share of imports increases the income, which can be explained by the microeconomic and macroeconomic assumptions of the models.

This model can be considered to be a consensus version of the various CGE models, which, in the simplest way, yields the same results as the multiple models making a high number of assumptions. Despite the detailed micro-level analysis of multivariate models, the macroeconomic growth effect can be calculated using the formula above. The idea behind the widespread applicability is that changes in welfare in each country depends only on changes in terms of trade, and on the other hand, changes in terms of trade can be deduced from changes in relative demand for each product in each country. Using this correlation, it can be demonstrated that, the change in real income can be determined by domestic use and trade elasticity (Arkolakis et al., 2012) – beside model prerequisites.

(5)

Thus, two types of data are needed to calculate the impact on real income: the change in the rate of domestic use and the value of trade elasticity. Trade elasticity has been estimated by several studies in different ways. As the purpose of this analysis was to quantify changes by industries besides the impact on total domestic GDP, that is why elasticity is also needed on the resilience of industries. Import prices are not properly decomposed in the HCSO database, therefore the industry data provided by Francois (2013) were used as a proxy in the model calculation. If not all HCSO (TEÁOT) industries were covered by the imported calculation, the elasticity of the higher industry aggregate was substituted. (E.g. the pharmaceutical industry did not receive a separate elasticity indicator, that is why the value of the chemical industry was taken into account.) It should be noted that the proxy data was calculated for EU-US, but as the study included overseas countries are studied, this may be an acceptable approximation between Hungary and the six trade partner countries in the analysis.

Table 1. Elasticity by Francois (2013)

Industry Price elasticity (ε) Agriculture, forestry and fishing 4.77

Mining and quarrying 12.13

food 2.46

beverages 2.46

tobacco 2.46

paper 7.99

chemical products 5.09

basic metals 13.91

fabricated metal products 13.91

electronic products 9.65

machinery 9.71

road transportation vehicle 10

other vehicle 7.14

other manufacturing 6.56

construction 4.21

Source: Francois (2013)

The analysis imports data about the use by sector from the input-output matrix of the Hungarian Central Statistical Office (HCSO). As the most last observation in the data set is 2015 at the time of the analysis, the model calculates with the data of 2015 in case of import decomposed by country and sector, which were imported also from the HCSO database. The study examines one scenario which reckons with a 90% tariff reduction and a 50% harmonization of non-tariff barriers.

(6)

Results of model calculation

Table 2. Impact of trade agreements on growth of Hungarian industrial and aggregate output, by CGE model calculation: Canada, Japan, South Korea

industry by sub-section (TEÁOR)

price elasticity

(ε)

EU-Canada

(CETA) EU-Japan EU-Korea Agriculture, forestry and fishing 4.77 -0.00545% -0.00008% -0.00004%

Mining and quarrying 12.13 -0.06144% -0.00006% -0.00001%

Manufacture of food products,

beverages and tobacco products 2.46 -0.00326% -0.00073% -0.00148%

Manufacture of textiles, apparel,

leather and related products 5 -0.00169% -0.00627% -0.10775%

Manufacture of wood and paper

products, and printing 7.99 -0.00101% -0.00596% -0.00170%

Manufacture of coke, and refined

petroleum products 5.09 0.00000% 0.00002% 0.00003%

Manufacture of chemicals and

chemical products 5 0.00014% 0.00542% 0.00302%

Manufacture of pharma-ceuticals, medicinal chemical and botanical

products 5 0.00021% 0.00025% 0.04435%

Manufacture of rubber and plastics products, and other non-metallic

mineral products 5 0.00028% 0.01007% 0.00334%

Manufacture of basic metals and fabricated metal products, except

machinery and equipment 13.91 0.00005% 0.00087% 0.00152%

Manufacture of computer,

electronic and optical products 5 0.00097% 0.01298% 0.04455%

Manufacture of electrical

equipment 9.65 0.00026% 0.00712% 0.00618%

Manufacture of machinery and

equipment n.e.c. 9.71 0.00005% 0.00102% 0.00029%

Manufacture of transport

equipment 10 0.00068% 0.02080% 0.00163%

Other manufacturing, and repair and installation of machinery and

equipment 6.56 -0.00003% -0.00008% -0.00004%

Construction 4.21 0.00000% 0.00000% 0.00000%

Total production 5 0.00018% 0.00182% 0.00208%

Regarding the effects of the agreement with the three developed countries, significant sectoral growth and additional GDP growth are not expected in the Hungarian economy, and unsurprisingly, significant surpluses can be generated by industries that are the leading sectors of the Hungarian economy, such as automotive, chemical/pharmaceutical industry and manufacture of electronic products. (Table 2)

(7)

In the case of emerging Latin American economies, the expected impact of sectoral output and additional GDP growth on Hungary is basically zero.

The model predicts a minimal decrease in the output of traditional industries (agriculture, food, textiles), which would not be surprising on the basis of comparative advantages, but it can also be considered as zero (Table 3).

Table 3. Impact of trade agreements on growth of Hungarian industrial and aggregate output, by CGE model calculation: Colombia, Peru, Ecuador

industry by sub-section (TEÁOR)

price elasticity

(ε)

EU-

Colombia EU-Peru EU-Ecuador Agriculture, forestry and fishing 4.77 -0.00001% -0.00002% -0.00004%

Mining and quarrying 12.13 0.00000% 0.00000% 0.00000%

Manufacture of food products, beverages and tobacco

products 2.46 -0.00068% -0.00014% -0.00018%

Manufacture of textiles, apparel, leather and related

products 5 -0.00001% -0.00047% -0.00003%

Manufacture of wood and paper

products, and printing 7.99 -0.00006% 0.00000% 0.00000%

Manufacture of coke, and

refined petroleum products 5.09 0.00000% 0.00000% 0.00000%

Manufacture of chemicals and

chemical products 5 0.00000% 0.00008% 0.00000%

Manufacture of pharma- ceuticals, medicinal chemical

and botanical products 5 0.00000% 0.00000% 0.00000%

Manufacture of rubber and plastics products, and other

non-metallic mineral products 5 0.00002% 0.00000% 0.00000%

Manufacture of basic metals and fabricated metal products, except machinery and

equipment 13.91 0.00000% 0.00000% 0.00000%

Manufacture of computer,

electronic and optical products 5 0.00000% 0.00000% 0.00000%

Manufacture of electrical

equipment 9.65 0.00000% 0.00000% 0.00000%

Manufacture of machinery and

equipment n.e.c. 9.71 0.00000% 0.00000% 0.00001%

Manufacture of transport

equipment 10 0.00000% 0.00000% 0.00000%

Other manufacturing, and repair and installation of

machinery and equipment 6.56 0.00000% 0.00000% 0.00000%

Construction 4.21 0.00000% 0.00000% 0.00000%

Total production 5 0.00000% 0.00000% 0.00000%

(8)

Conclusion

The study provided an overview of the methodology for examining the impact of EU agreements on the Hungarian economy. Based on the methodology of the presented CGE model, the study contained the impact assessment of the Hungarian sectoral output and GDP growth originates in six trade agreements and economic partnerships in which the European Union has contracted or intended to establish pact with overseas economies: Canada, Korea, Japan, Colombia, Peru, Ecuador.

The CGE model calculation shows that no significant effect is expected from the certain EU trade pacts themselves for Hungary. In the case of Japan, Canada or Korea, which are represented by big transnational companies in Hungary, the explanation can be that Hungary has been already included into corporate value chains in large volume. However, in the case of the three Latin American countries, the low level of sectoral relations is also due to the economic, geographical and cultural distance at which the EU-agreement can result in some "invisible change" only in commodity sectors.

References

Anderson, J. E. (1979). A theoretical foundation for the gravity equation. The American Economic Review. 69 (1), 106-116.

Anderson, J. E., & Van Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93 (1), 170-192.

Arkolakis, C., Costinot, A., & Andres R.-C. (2012). New Trade Models, Same Old Gains American Economic Review, 102 (1), 94-130.

Baldwin, R. E., & Francois, J. (1997). Transatlantic Trade Liberalization – A Computable General Equilibrium Analysis, a report for the United Kingdom.

London: Foreign and Commonwealth Office.

Berden, K., Francois, J. F., Tamminen, S., Thelle, M., & Wymenga, P. (2009).

Non-Tariff Measures in EU-US Trade and Investment – An Economic Analysis.

[Final Report for EC DG-Trade, Reference OJ 2007/S180-219493]. Rotterdam:

ECORYS.

Bergstrand, J. (1985) The gravity equation in international trade: some

microeconomic foundations and empirical evidence. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 67 (3), 474-481.

Caliendo, L., & Parro, F (2014). Estimates of the Trade and Welfare Effects of NAFTA,Review of Economic Studies, 82 (1), 1-44.

Dekle, R., Eaton, J., & Kortum, S. (2008). Global Rebalancing with Gravity:

Measuring the Burden of Adjustment. IMF Staff Papers, 55 (3), 511-540.

DG-Trade (2017). The economic impact of the Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement (CETA). European Commission’s Directorate-General for Trade.

DG-Trade (2018). The economic impact of the EU-Japan Economic Partnership Agreement (EPA). European Commission’s Directorate-General for Trade.

(9)

European Commission (2016). Assessing the economic impact of the Trade

Agreement between the European Union and Ecuador. Assessing the economic impact of the accession of Ecuador to the EU-Colombia/Peru Trade Agreement.

European Commission.

Felbermayr, G. J., Schmerer, H-J., & Prat, J. (2011). Globalization and labor market outcomes: Wage bargaining, search frictions, and firm heterogeneity.

Journal of Economic Theory, 146 (1), 39-73.

Felbermayr, G. J., Jung, B., & Larch, M. (2013b). Icebergs versus Tariffs: A Quantitative Perspective on the Gains from Trade. CESifo Working Paper, No.

4175, CESifo.

Felbermayr, G. J., Lehwald, S., & Heid, B. (2013a). Transatlantic Trade and Invetment Partnership (TTIP): Who benefits from a free trade deal? Part 1:

Macroeconomic Effects. Gütersloh: Bertelsmann Stiftung; Global Economic Dynamics (GED) Team.

Forizs V., & Nilsson, L. (2016). Trade effects of the EU-Korea Free Trade

Agreement: A comparative anyalysis of expected and observed outcomes. DG- Trade Chief Economist Note Issue 3.

Francois, J. (2013). Reducing Transatlantic Barriers to Trade and Investment: An Economic Assessment. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.

Francois, J., McDonald, B., & Nordström, H. (1996). Liberalization and Capital Accumulation in the GTAP Model. GTAP Technical Paper Series No 07. Center for Global Trade Analysis; Purdue University.

Kutasi, G. (2015). A Transzatlanti kereskedelmi és beruházási társulás és a növekedés: Gyakorlati és módszertani kérdések. Közgazdaság, 10 (3), 57-71.

Kutasi, G., Rezessy, G., & Szijártó, N. (2014). Az USA-EU kereskedelmi

tárgyalások várható hatása a magyar növekedésre. Külgazdaság, 58 (7-8), 58-85.

Lakatos Cs., & Nilsson, L. (2015). The EU-Korea ree trade Agreement:

Anticipation, trade policy, Uncertainity and Impact. DG-Trade Chief Economist Note Issue 2.

Palánkai Tibor, Benczes István, Jodi Jensen, Kengyel Ákos, Kutasi Gábor, & Nagy Sándor Gyula (2014). Economics of Global and Regional Integration.

Budapest: Akadémiai.

Zalai Ernő (1998). Általános egyensúlyi modellek alkalmazása gazdaságpolitikai elemzésekre. Közgazdasági Szemle, 45 (11), 1065-1081.

Hivatkozások

KAPCSOLÓDÓ DOKUMENTUMOK

The results of the effected regressions within this study based on the gravitational model of the international trade show that trade agreements extended by the EU to the Republic

The second, equally important, aspect of the distinction between output and in- come concerns the macroeconomic impact of changes in the terms of trade on aggre- gate domestic

However, as agricultural imports grew more dynamically than total imports, the share of agricultural products in total imports in case of the V 4 countries grew from 4.9 percent

Moreover, taking part in the insolvency agreement proceedings, tax authorities should not be guided only by the fiscal principle because it is against the principle of social market

These new-generation free trade agreements cover the whole spectrum of trade (goods, services, technology, capital, etc.) and do not restrict themselves to demolishing

Major research areas of the Faculty include museums as new places for adult learning, development of the profession of adult educators, second chance schooling, guidance

The decision on which direction to take lies entirely on the researcher, though it may be strongly influenced by the other components of the research project, such as the

In this article, I discuss the need for curriculum changes in Finnish art education and how the new national cur- riculum for visual art education has tried to respond to