• Nem Talált Eredményt

Two types of eects of price change

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Ossza meg "Two types of eects of price change"

Copied!
37
0
0

Teljes szövegt

(1)

MICROECONOMICS I.

(2)
(3)
(4)

ELTE Faculty of Social Sciences, Department of Economics

Microeconomics I.

week 8

CONSUMPTION AND DEMAND, PART 2 Authors:

Gergely K®hegyi, Dániel Horn, Klára Major Supervised by

Gergely K®hegyi

June 2010

(5)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

The course was prepaerd by Gergely K®hegyi, using Jack Hirshleifer, Amihai Glazer and David Hirshleifer (2009) Mikroökonómia. Budapest: Osiris Kiadó, ELTECON-books (henceforth HGH), and Gábor Kertesi (ed.) (2004) Mikroökonómia el®adásvázlatok.

http://econ.core.hu/ kertesi/kertesimikro/ (henceforth KG).

(6)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Approaches to income compensation

How should the government compensate for the eects of price change, which made some groups in the society worse o?

(7)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Two types of eects of price change

The eect of price change upon consumer demand may be separated into two components.

Fall in Px increases the consumer's real income. He or she could buy the same bundle of goods as before, and have something left over. If X is a superior good, the consumer will use some of the excess to buy more X This is called the income eect of the fall in Px

Furthermore, at the lower Px the substitution balance equation tells us that even if real income or utility had remained the same, more X would have been purchased. This is called the pure substitution eect of the price change.

(8)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Two types of eects of price change (cont.)

(9)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Hicks decomposition

(10)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Hicks decomposition (cont.)

A fall in price Px with income and Py held constant shifts in the budget line from KL to KL0 so that the consumption optimum changes from Q to S. Because S lies on a higher indierence curve, there has been an increase in real income. We construct an articial budget line MN parallel to KL0 and tangent to the original indierence curve U0. The income eect of the price change is therefore xS−xR and the pure substitution eect of the price change is xR−xQ.

(11)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

How can the Gien case come about?

A Gien good must have the following properties.

It must be inferior, so that the income eect of a price change is negative.

It must account for a large fraction of the budget. This makes the "perverse" income eect large in magnitude. (It has to be large if it is to overcome the pure substitution eect.)

(12)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

How can the Gien case come about? (cont.)

At the initial high bread price the budget line is KL and the optimum is Q. A fall in the price of bread shifts the budget line to KL0. The consumer is suciently enriched to prefer buying less bread and more meat at point R. The movement from Q to R consists of a small substitution eect (Q to S) and a large negative income eect (S to R). For this Gien result to occur, bread must be strongly inferior.

(13)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Utility maximization

maximize: U(x,y)→maxx,y

subject to: pxx+pyy=I Lagrange-function:

L(x,y, λ) =U(x,y)−λ(pxx+pyy−I)

∂L

x = Ux −λpx =0

∂L

y = Uy −λpy =0

∂L

∂λ =Pxx+Pyy−I =0

The Marshall demand function:

xM(px,py,I) yM(px,py,I)

(14)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Expenditure minimization

minimize: pxx+pyy →minx,y

subject to: U(x,y) = ¯U =U(x0,y0) Lagrange-function:

L(x,y, λ) =pxx+pyy−λ(U(x,y)−U¯)

∂L

x =px−λUx =0

∂L

y =py−λUy =0

∂L

∂λ =U(x,y)−U¯ =0

The Hicks demand function:

xH(px,py,U¯) yH(px,py,U¯)

(15)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Expenditure function and indirect utility

Denition

Indirect utility function: The value of the utility maximization in the optimum, which depends on the exogenous px,py,I variables and which shows the maximal level of utility of the consumer at the given prices and income:

v(px,py,I) ={max(U(x,y))|pxx+pyy=I}

Denition

Expenditure function: The value of the expenditure minimization in the optimum, which depends on the exogenous px,py,U¯ variables and which shows the minimal amount of expenditure by which the given utility level can be achieved (at given prices):

e(px,py,U¯) ={min(pxx+pyy)|U(x,y) = ¯U}

(16)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Duality

Statement

SHEPHARD-LEMMA

∂e(px,py,U¯)

∂px =xH(px,py,U¯)

∂e(px,py,U¯)

∂py =yH(px,py,U¯)

(17)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Duality (cont.)

Proof

Let(p0x,py0)be arbitrary prices andU arbitrary level of utility, and¯ (x0,y0)be the solution of the expenditure minimization function for the three given parameters. Let's dene

f(px,py)≡pxx0+pyy0−e(px,py,U¯)

function for an arbitrary(px,py). Since e(px,py,U¯)is the minimal expenditure for(px,py,U¯)

f(px,py)≥0

always holds. And if (px,py) = (px0,p0y), then f(p0x,py0) =0 takes its minimum. Then

(18)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Duality

Proof

∂f(px,py)

∂px =x0−∂e(px,py,U¯)

∂px =0

∂f(px,py)

∂py =y0−∂e(px,py,U¯)

∂py =0

Since(p0x,py0)were arbitrary prices, the above relation holds for any set of prices:

∂e(px,py,U¯)

∂px =xH(px,py,U¯)

∂e(px,py,U¯)

∂py =yH(px,py,U¯)

(19)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Duality

(20)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Duality

e(px,py,v(px,py,I)) =I v(px,py,e(px,py,U¯)) = ¯U

e(px,py,U¯) =pxxH(px,py,U¯) +pyyH(px,py,U¯) v(px,py,I) =U xM(px,py,I),yM(px,py,I)

(21)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Slutsky-theorem

Statement

Slutsky-theorem

∂xM px,py,e(px,py,U¯)

∂px = ∂xH(px,py,U¯)

∂px −∂xM

∂e xM

∂xM px,py,e(px,py,U¯)

∂py =∂xH(px,py,U¯)

∂py −∂xM

∂e yM

∂yM px,py,e(px,py,U¯)

∂px =∂yH(px,py,U¯)

∂px −∂yM

∂e xM

∂yM px,py,e(px,py,U¯)

∂py =∂yH(px,py,U¯)

∂py −∂yM

∂e yM

(22)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Slutsky-theorem

Proof

Due to duality relations:

xM px,py,e(px,py,U¯)

=xH(px,py,U¯) yM px,py,e(px,py,U¯)

=yH(px,py,U¯)

(23)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Slutsky-theorem

Proof

Partially dierentiating both equations with both prices:

∂xM

∂px +∂xM

∂e

∂e

∂px =∂xH

∂px

∂xM

∂py +∂xM

∂e

∂e

∂py =∂xH

∂py

∂yM

∂px +∂yM

∂e

∂e

∂px =∂yH

∂px

∂yM

∂py +∂yM

∂e

∂e

∂py =∂yH

∂py

(24)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Slutsky-theorem

Proof

Using the Shephard-lemma and rearranging the equation:

∂xM

∂px = ∂xH

∂px −∂xM

∂e xH

∂xM

∂py = ∂xH

∂py −∂xM

∂e yH

∂yM

∂px = ∂yH

∂px −∂yM

∂e xH

∂yM

∂py = ∂yH

∂py −∂yM

∂e yH

(25)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Slutsky-theorem

Proof

Using duality relations we get the Slutsky-theorem:

∂xM

∂px =∂xH

∂px −∂xM

∂e xM

∂xM

∂py = ∂xH

∂py −∂xM

∂e yM

∂yM

∂px = ∂yH

∂px −∂yM

∂e xM

∂yM

∂py = ∂yH

∂py −∂yM

∂e yM

(26)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

A little more precise, mathematically

xM =

 x1M xi...M xn...M

 ,xH =

 x1H x...iH x...nH

 ,p=

 p1

p...i p...n

Expenditure function:

e(p,U¯) ={min(px|U(x) = ¯U} Shephard-lemma:

∇e(p,U¯) =xH

(27)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

A little more precise, mathematically (cont.)

Marshall substitution matrix:

M=

x1M

p1

x1M

p2 · · · xp1M

i . . . xp1M

n

x2M

p1

x2M

p2 · · · xp2M

i . . . xp2M ... ... n

x1M

pi

xiM

pi ...

... ... ...

x1M

pn · · · xpnM

n

(28)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

A little more precise, mathematically (cont.)

Hicks substitution matrix:

H=

x1H

p1

x1H

p2 · · · xp1H

i . . . xp1H

n

x2H

p1

x2H

p2 · · · xp2H

i . . . xp2H ... ... n

x1H

pi

xiH

pi ...

... ... ...

x1H

pn · · · xpnH

n

(29)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

A little more precise, mathematically (cont.)

Slutsky-matrix

S=

x1M

p1 +x1eMx1M · · · xp1M

n +xe1MxnM

... ... ...

... xpiMi +xeiMxiM ...

... ... ...

xnM

p1 +xneMx1M · · · xpnM

n +xenMxnM

Slutsky-theorem:

S=H

Statement

The Hicks substitution matrix is symmetrical xpHi

j = xpjH

i and has non-positive elements in the main diagonal xpiHi ≤0.

(30)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

A little more precise, mathematically (cont.)

(31)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

A little more precise, mathematically (cont.)

Proof (draft)

Symmetry comes from the Young-theorem.

py≤px qx≤qy (q−p)(y−x)≤0

(q1−p1)(y1−x1) + (q2−p2)(y2−x2)≤0 Let's assume that q2=p2, then

(q1−p1)(y1−x1)≤0

∆pi∆xi|U=U0≤0

limpi0

∆xi

∆pi|U=U0 ≤0

∂xiH

∂pi ≤0

(32)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

A little more precise, mathematically

Consequence

The main diagonal of the Slutsky matrix has non-positive elements.

Consequence

LAW of DEMAND: If good i is a normal good, then xpiMi ≤0, which means that its demand curve has a negative slope.

Proof

Since in the Hicks matrix xpiH

i ≤0, therefore in the Slutsky matrix

xiM

pi +xieMxiM ≤0. For normal goods xeiM >0, thus necessarily

xiM

pi ≤0.

(33)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Slutsky decomposition

maximize: U(x,y)→maxx,y

subject to: pxx+pyy=pxx0+pyy0

Lagrange-functions:

L(x,y, λ) =U(x,y)−λ(pxx+pyy−pxx0−pyy0)

∂L

x = Ux −λpx =0

∂L

y = Uy −λpy =0

∂L

∂λ =Pxx+Pyy−pxx0−pyy0=0

Slutsky demand functions:

xS(px,py,x0,y0) yS(px,py,x0,y0)

(34)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Slutsky decomposition (cont.)

Statement

Slutsky theorem[with Slutsky decomposition]

∂xM(px,py,pxx0+pyy0))

∂px = ∂xS(px,py,x0,y0)

∂px −∂xM

∂I x0

∂xM(px,py,pxx0+pyy0))

∂py = ∂xS(px,py,x0,y0)

∂py −∂xM

∂I y0

∂yM(px,py,pxx0+pyy0))

∂px = ∂yS(px,py,x0,y0)

∂px −∂yM

∂I x0

∂yM(px,py,pxx0+pyy0))

∂py = ∂yS(px,py,x0,y0)

∂py −∂yM

∂I y0

(35)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Market demand

Summing individual demands

X ≡

N

X

i=1

xi

Here d1and d2are demand curves for two individuals. If these are the only two potential purchasers of the good, the overall market demand curve D is the horizontal sum of d1 and d2.

(36)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Subsidy versus voucher

(37)

week 8

K®hegyi-Horn-Major

Income and substitution eects of a price change

Subsidy versus voucher (cont.)

Voucher

The initial optimum is a corner solution at K; no education is purchased. A voucher gift of income in the amount KK0 leads to a new optimum at K00 The voucher leads to an increased consumption of education, provided only that education is a good rather than a bad for this individual.

Hivatkozások

KAPCSOLÓDÓ DOKUMENTUMOK

Major research areas of the Faculty include museums as new places for adult learning, development of the profession of adult educators, second chance schooling, guidance

Therefore, this raises questions for the governance of reform, including what types of accountability, trust, pro- fessionalism or leadership can foster a culture of innovation

The decision on which direction to take lies entirely on the researcher, though it may be strongly influenced by the other components of the research project, such as the

In this article, I discuss the need for curriculum changes in Finnish art education and how the new national cur- riculum for visual art education has tried to respond to

The coefficient of cross-price elasticity of demand may be positive when the increasing price of another product leads to an increasing demand for our commodity (which is

rather than the percentage of available hemoglobin bound to 0 2.. If the oxygen consumption of a man at rest is taken as 250 ml/min and the cardiac output is 5 liters/min, then

The cross-price elasticity of demand is the proportionate change in quantity purchased divided by the proportionate change in price of another good..

The cross-price elasticity of demand is the proportionate change in quantity purchased divided by the proportionate change in price of another good.. Relations