• Nem Talált Eredményt

LABOR ECONOMICS

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Ossza meg "LABOR ECONOMICS"

Copied!
10
0
0

Teljes szövegt

(1)

LABOR ECONOMICS

Sponsored by a Grant TÁMOP-4.1.2-08/2/A/KMR-2009-0041 Course Material Developed by Department of Economics,

Faculty of Social Sciences, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest (ELTE) Department of Economics, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest

Institute of Economics, Hungarian Academy of Sciences Balassi Kiadó, Budapest

Author: János Köllő Supervised by: János Köllő

January 2011

(2)

2

LABOR ECONOMICS

Week 3

Labor supply – Measurement

János Köllő

Estimating the static labor supply model

On the estimation of the life-cycle model

•The slides on the estimation of the static labor supply model follow Galasi (1995) and draw from Gábor Kertesi’s lectures at Rajk College (manuscript)

Galasi Péter: A munkanélküliek piaci munkakínálata és a munkanélküliségi mérõszámok értékelése, Közgazdasági Szemle, XLII. évf., 1995. 3. sz.

(236–255. o.)

•The last two slides draw from a lecture note by Peter Kuhn, downloadable at:

http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~pjkuhn/Ec250A/Class%20Notes/C_DynamicLS.pdf

•Other sources are referred to in the text

(3)

3

Estimating the static labor supply model

Why not estimate a supply equation directly with OLS?

Because we observe wages (w) and hours (H) only for those at work. However, those out of work may also have wage offers and may have non-zero supply of hours.

Those at work are not randomly selected and it is almost sure that:

A remark on treating unemployment

•The decision to enter the labor force is governed by the relation of the market wage (w) to the reservation wage (wR). w>wR is a necessary but insufficient condition of having a job and an observable wage. Demand-side factors matter, too.

•In fact we have three states. If is the observed wage:

In the empirical model we start by making distinction between two states only. If H is observed hours and is observed wage, we have:

The key question is how the second group is selected.

Technically, this is a missing variable problem.

) employed (

0 , 0 job

a got and

) unemployed (

. , 0 job

no got and

) inactive (

. , 0

H w

w

H w

w

H w

w

R i i

R i i

R i i

i i i

i

i

X w y u

H

) , , (

.) ,

,

( H X y w E H X y w

E

(4)

4 In order to account for non-random selection we have to model:

E1) Selection to work: what factors determine the probability that an individual has non-missing wage data?

E2) The distribution of wage offers: given the patterns of selection analysed in E1, what is the expected wage of those out of work?

E3) The link between wage offers and the supply of working hours: to be estimated for the entire population including those out of work.

In empirical research, a system of equations E1–E3 is customarily used to estimate the elasticity of labor supply with respect to wages and non-wage income.

E1) Selection to workAssume that individual i-s marginal utility from working is

systematically related to a series of personal and environmental characteristics (Zi) and also affected by unobserved attributes (ui).

• For those at work (D=1) marginal utility from entering employment is positive. If u is normally distributed, then:

• One can estimate the g-s with maximum likelihood (probit):E2) The distribution of wage offers

• Wage offers also depend on a series of observed characteristics (Xi) and

unobserved attributes (ei): wi = bXi + ei.We would like to estimate the expectation of w. However, we observe wages conditional on ui being larger than -gZi. It can be shown that:The estimation of expected wages thus involves the following steps*:

1. Estimate an employment probit [Pr(D=1)=f(Z)] for the entire population to get the g- s. Calculate the so-called inverse Mills ratios (li= f(-gZi)/ (1-F(-gZi)) for each

observation.

2. Estimate an OLS wage regression with Xi and li on the right hand.

0 1

) - ( ) ) ( - (1 max

D

i D

i Z

Z L

(5)

5 3. Before you do so, look at the conditions for full identification and study the test

statistics in Wooldridge (2002, 560–566), Greene (1999,707–713) and elsewhere.

*) This is the two-step procedure of Heckman (1979, Econometrica). The system can be estimated with FIML, too

Notes to interpreting the wage equation:

• The covariates affect wages directly (through b) and indirectly (through l).

) (

) ( ) - ( - 1

) - (

) - ( )

- )

1

) , , 1 , 0 , 0 (

~ ) , (

i i i

i i

u i

i i

i

u i

i

Z Z Z

Z

Z u

E(w D

E(w

N u

=

= where

+

=

>

=

=

is wages observed

of n expectatio l

conditiona The

that assumption the

Under

γZ βX

(6)

6

• The direction of selection bias depends on the sign of the correlation between unobserved attributes affecting wages and the probability of having a job (reu).

X is a subset of Z (all factors affecting the wage affect the probability of working).

Normally, we need at least one Z-variable, that is not part of X.

• Using the parameters and observing X and Z, you can predict offer wages for all members of the population. An example:

HLFS, 2001 Q2 Women aged 15-64 Exp: experience iskev: years in school bpest: Budapest

nkisgye: number of children aged 0–6

famstat1: married

kshreg: region dummies

The OLS estimate

heckman lnwnetto iskev exp exp2 bpest if nem==0 & kor>14 & kor<65 & nem<. & fogl1<5, select(iskev exp exp2 famstat1 nkisgye kshreg1 kshreg3-kshreg7) twostep

Heckman selection model -- two-step estimates Number of obs = 28702 (regression model with sample selection) Censored obs = 18000 Uncensored obs = 10702 Wald chi2(4) = 1831.77 Prob > chi2 = 0.0000 --- | Coef. Std. Err. z P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval]

---+--- lnwnetto |

iskev | .0483015 .0015209 31.76 0.000 .0453207 .0512824 exp | .0018412 .0021105 0.87 0.383 -.0022953 .0059776 exp2 | .0000347 .0000476 0.73 0.466 -.0000586 .000128 bpest | .1460012 .0102205 14.29 0.000 .1259695 .166033 _cons | 10.03622 .0467152 214.84 0.000 9.944656 10.12778 ---+--- select |

iskev | .0722939 .0032863 22.00 0.000 .0658529 .0787349 exp | .1291689 .0030901 41.80 0.000 .1231124 .1352255 exp2 | -.0030021 .0000603 -49.75 0.000 -.0031204 -.0028838 famstat1 | -.0816009 .029013 -2.81 0.005 -.1384652 -.0247365 nkisgye | -.4717529 .0180457 -26.14 0.000 -.5071218 -.4363841 kshreg1 | -.3401098 .030188 -11.27 0.000 -.3992772 -.2809424 kshreg3 | -.1875587 .0340299 -5.51 0.000 -.2542561 -.1208614 kshreg4 | -.2776233 .0347729 -7.98 0.000 -.345777 -.2094696 kshreg5 | -.2035106 .0330889 -6.15 0.000 -.2683638 -.1386575 kshreg6 | -.2299434 .0317025 -7.25 0.000 -.2920792 -.1678075 kshreg7 | -.2325834 .0326939 -7.11 0.000 -.2966623 -.1685045 _cons | -1.575283 .0608592 -25.88 0.000 -1.694565 -1.456001 ---+--- mills |

lambda | -.0557418 .0201843 -2.76 0.006 -.0953024 -.0161813 ---+--- rho | -0.18910

sigma | .294772

lambda | -.05574183 .0201843

---

. fit lnwnetto iskev exp exp2 bpest if nem==0 & kor>14 & kor<65 & nem<. & fogl1<5 Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 10702 ---+--- F( 4, 10697) = 618.06 Model | 210.232088 4 52.558022 Prob > F = 0.0000 Residual | 909.636758 10697 .085036623 R-squared = 0.1877 ---+--- Adj R-squared = 0.1874 Total | 1119.86885 10701 .104650859 Root MSE = .29161 --- lnwnetto | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]

---+--- iskev | .0510044 .0011588 44.02 0.000 .048733 .0532757 exp | .0069127 .0010382 6.66 0.000 .0048776 .0089478 exp2 | -.0000794 .0000236 -3.36 0.001 -.0001257 -.0000331 bpest | .1414495 .0100771 14.04 0.000 .1216964 .1612025 _cons | 9.916388 .0172336 575.41 0.000 9.882607 9.95017 ---

(7)

7 E3) Hours of work as a function of wage offersNow we have estimates for the wage offer ( ).

The problem of selection bias is present here, too à include l.Estimate OLS:

We estimate the equation using data on those at work (H>0) but the predictions yield information on all members of the population.

See Galasi (1995) for an example of estimating the hours supply of different groups of unemployed people in Hungary (active job seekers, registered unemployed, benefit recipients, etc.).

The hours equation for the LFS sub-sample:

Women aged 15–64

Any clue to judge if our estimates make sense?

i i i i

i

w Z v

H =

1

ˆ +

2

+ +

fit lnaltfoa iskev exp exp2 logu nyug gyes gyed ua ln_wage lambda if nem==0 &

kor>14 & kor<65 & nem<. & fogl1<5 & altfoa>0

Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 11097 ---+--- F( 10, 11086) = 98.46 Model | 22.5160195 10 2.25160195 Prob > F = 0.0000 Residual | 253.520223 11086 .022868503 R-squared = 0.0816 ---+--- Adj R-squared = 0.0807 Total | 276.036243 11096 .024877095 Root MSE = .15122 --- lnaltfoa | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]

---+--- iskev | -.01871 .0026179 -7.15 0.000 -.0238415 -.0135785 exp | -.0011307 .0008211 -1.38 0.169 -.0027402 .0004788 exp2 | .0000125 .0000179 0.70 0.484 -.0000225 .0000476 logu | .0057415 .0028571 2.01 0.045 .0001411 .0113419 nyug | -.3359047 .0138853 -24.19 0.000 -.3631224 -.3086871 gyes | -.223816 .0176189 -12.70 0.000 -.2583522 -.1892799 gyed | -.0765754 .031734 -2.41 0.016 -.1387798 -.014371 ua | -.5703937 .047853 -11.92 0.000 -.6641941 -.4765932 ln_wageoffer | .2053451 .0342571 5.99 0.000 .1381951 .2724952 lambda | -.0322695 .0096537 -3.34 0.001 -.0511924 -.0133466 _cons | 2.757972 .1626435 16.96 0.000 2.439162 3.076782 ---

(8)

8 a) Hicksian elasticites should be positive.

b) The Marshallian (M) and Hicksian (H ) elasticites should not differ substantially.

Why?

Let us start with the supply equation:

In terms of elasticities:

Therefore, for the two elasticities (M, H):

mpe – the „marginal propensity to earn out of nonwage income* – shows how a unit increase in non-wage income affects earned income by reducing working hours

mpe versus mpc

Let us differentiate the budget constraint (Y+wT=X+wL Y+wH=X) by Y

What is X/ Y? It is the marginal propensity to consume (mpc), a parameter expected to fall close to 1. Savings seldom exceed 0.3 so mpc typically falls somewhere between 0.7 and 1.

*) As called in Pencavel 1986, Handbook of Labor Economics Therefore we have:

where is a small negative number somewhere in the range of 0/-0.3. To the extent it is true, the compensated and uncompensated elasticities should not differ substantially.

I H H w

H w H

U U 0

I w H H

w w

H H

w w H

U U 0

I mpe w H H H

M

I mpe w H H H

M

mpc Y mpe

X Y

w H 1

1

1

1 mpc

mpc

mpe H M H

H

M

(9)

9 Let us now utilise this piece of knowledge for the evaluation of some empirical estimates following Pencavel (1986).

Results from 22 studies on US and UK males*

Marshallian elasticites Hicksian elasticites

Source: Pencavel (1986), Tables 1.19 and 1.20.

Results from 22 studies on US and UK males*

-.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1

mean of marshall 14

2 187 10 128 135 22 19 15 214 1691 116 173 20

Marshall-féle rugalmasságok

-.2 0 .2 .4 .6 .8

mean of hicks 14

10 21 15 19 188 20 4 173 2 1 13 127 9 22 16 5 116

Hicks-féle rugalmasságok

.2.4.6.8 1

Implicit fogyasztási határhajlandóság

-.2 0 .2 .4 .6 .8

Hicks-féle rugalmasságok

Hicksian elasticities Implicit MPC .2.4.6.8 1

Implicit fogyasztási határhajlandóság

-.2 0 .2 .4 .6 .8

Hicks-féle rugalmasságok

Hicksian elasticities

Implicit MPC

(10)

10 Values outside the yellow area are hard to accept given the wrong sign of H and/or the too low/too high value of mpc

Source: Pencavel (1986), Tables 1.19 and 1.20.

On estimating the life-cycle model

•Assume we have longitudinal (panel) data on the wages and working hours of individuals within a group of people (wit, Hit).

•Let us write the Frisch demand functions where the demand for leisure (and the supply of working hours) depend on the:

– current wage

– relation of the interest rate to the discount factor characteristic of the sub- population ( )

– marginal utility of lifetime income ( )

– a set of time-varying (X) and time-invarying (c) variables affecting individuals’

propensity to work

Hivatkozások

KAPCSOLÓDÓ DOKUMENTUMOK

The goals of the study: to determine on the basis of sociological data share of active (including those employed and unemployed) and inactive population in composition of

In this article, I discuss the need for curriculum changes in Finnish art education and how the new national cur- riculum for visual art education has tried to respond to

By examining the factors, features, and elements associated with effective teacher professional develop- ment, this paper seeks to enhance understanding the concepts of

Deriving the static labor supply model Household production and labor supply The life-cycle model of labor supply Added and discouraged workers Benefits and labor supply..

For people already at work, a rise in w may increase or decrease labor supply because the income effect and the substitution effect work in the opposite direction. For people out

• Increase in w and r increases labor supply through intertemporal substitution, an increase in the present value of income decreases labor supply through the increase of demand

• Labor demand and supply are functions of the real wage, just as they are in the RBC model.. • However, if the nominal wage is rigid, then the real wage (W/P) cannot clear the

• Labor demand and supply are functions of the real wage, just as they are in the RBC model?. • However, if the nominal wage is rigid, then the real wage (W/P) cannot clear the